96
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Special Issue: Transcending Western-Centrism and Nationalism: China and Beyond

Education as capital? A critical discourse analysis of the investment discourse in international research on Chinese rural education

ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon, ORCID Icon &
Received 23 Feb 2024, Accepted 08 Nov 2024, Published online: 20 Nov 2024

ABSTRACT

This article examines the rise of human capital theory and the investment discourse in education with a focus on Chinese rural education. We carry out Critical Discourse Analysis on 38 research articles published in highly cited English-language social science journals between 1978 and 2022. We demonstrate that Chinese rural education boomed as a topic of international research in the 21st century due to intensified academic internationalisation in China, which is intertwined with China’s pursuit of global influence and rising nationalism. The articles in our sample respond more to mainstream discourses dominated by the Global North than to the concerns of local communities, thereby reinforcing the dominance of western social theories and discourses like the human capital theory and the investment discourse. Amidst increasingly antagonistic global politics, we call for the critical ‘double negation’ (this issue) of both coloniality and nationalism to open up possibilities of plural knowledges.

Introduction

Since the 1960s, human capital theory has become a mainstay in educational research and policy despite continued critiques (Klees Citation2016). Employed to analyse a wide spectrum of human affairs, human capital theory utilises terms from the economics discipline to construct a framework that places education at the centre of social analysis. It claims that education contributes to economic development at the macro level and income growth at the micro level through increasing workers’ skills and productivity (Tan Citation2014). In the face of rising economic inequalities and humanitarian crises around the globe, human capital theory ‘offers the comforting illusion that for every complex social and economic problem there is one simple solution’ – education (Tan Citation2014, 432).

In this article, we examine the rise and impact of human capital theory and the related investment discourse in educational research with a focus on Chinese rural education, a marginal yet rapidly growing topic in global knowledge production (Xiang et al. Citation2023). We define the investment discourse in education as the symbolic system that constructs education as a form of investment in human capital with the potential of yielding private and public economic returns. Key discursive constructions associated with the investment discourse include human capital, skills, productivity, return to education, wage differentials and efficiency.

The goal of this paper is to unpack the asymmetric power relations and dynamic processes that undergird the spread and dominance of human capital theory and the investment discourse to open up possibilities of plural knowledges. More than half a century after the ostensible end of classic colonialism, the modernity-coloniality nexus persists in global knowledge production (Mignolo Citation2011). While scholars outside the colonial core increasingly contribute to English-language social science knowledge production, the universality and centrality of Western social theories and methodologies to a large extent remains taken-for-granted (Chen Citation2010; Mignolo Citation2011). Even fields like comparative and international education have given little attention to ‘the critical role that uneven power relations play in the constitution of its comparative knowledge’ (Takayama, Sriprakash, and Connell Citation2017, 3).

As Chinese scholars with transnational educational and professional experiences, we recognise the precarity associated with examining China through the lens of decoloniality. On the one hand, though Western powers never managed to fully colonise China, Chinese scholars encounter the persistent colonial matrix of power (Mignolo Citation2011) in global knowledge production like other Global South scholars. On the other hand, China is a rising global power eager to expand its ‘discourse power’ (Xinhua News Agency Citation2013) in increasingly antagonistic global political landscapes, which often prompts questions about whether it seeks to become the next global superpower with imperial or colonial ambitions. Therefore, we echo this special issue’s call for the ‘double-negation’ (this issue) of coloniality and nationalism. We critically examine the asymmetric power relations in global knowledge production as well as the roles of the Chinese state and Chinese scholars in maintaining, modifying or transforming them.

Toward the afore-mentioned goals, we utilise a dataset of research articles about Chinese rural education published in 40 highly-cited English language academic journals between 1978 (the start of Reform and Opening Up in China) and 2022. We described the sample selection criteria and abductive coding process in detail elsewhere (Xiang et al. Citation2023) and provide the list of included journals in the online supplement. In sum, our sample includes the most cited journals (based on Impact Factor and CiteScore) in major social science disciplines and fields related to Chinese rural education, such as sociology, economics, comparative education, child development and sinology. We focus on these journals to construct a sample of dominant voices in global knowledge production. We by no means endorse them as more legitimate or trustworthy sources of knowledge.

Of the 171 articles related to Chinese rural education published in these journals between 1978 and 2022, 52 (30%) were influenced by and 38 (22%) were primarily framed through human capital theory and the investment discourse.Footnote1 In this article, we further carried out discourse analysis on the subsample of 38 articles to unpack the asymmetric power relations and dynamic processes underlying the growth of Chinese rural education as an area of international research and the growing prominence of the investment discourse within it. We draw inspirations from Critical Discourse Analysis (Wodak, Seale, and Gobo Citation2004) and Foucauldian Discourse Analysis (Willig Citation2013) to construct an analytic framework suitable for our mission and sample. Specifically, we analysed the 38 texts in our sample at three levels: text, discursive practice, and social practice. At the textual level, we seek to identify the key discourse constructions, subject positions and action implications embedded in sample texts, with a focus on introduction and discussion/conclusion sections where authors spell out the conceptual frameworks and implications of their work. At the level of discursive practice, we investigate intertextuality and discursive environments through tracing references, data sources and author bios. At the level of social practice, we examine how these texts interact with changing economic, political and sociocultural dynamics in China and around the globe.

Our analysis reveals that the articles in our sample ask and answer questions about Chinese rural education through the lenses of neo-classical economic theories – especially human capital theory – usually without critical examination of the methodological, cultural and political assumptions baked into these theories. Therefore, though most first authors bear Chinese surnames, these articles reinforce rather than challenge the hegemony of Western economic theories and the persistent coloniality in global academic production.

The rest of the article consists of four sections. First, we briefly review the origins and the rise of human capital theory and the investment discourse in educational research and policy. Second, we examine the growth of Chinese rural education as an area of international research and the rise of the investment discourse within this expanding body of literature. Third, we describe and analyse the discursive characteristics of the four major clusters of articles among those framed through the investment discourse. Finally, we conclude with a discussion of the implications of our findings for comparative and international education researchers, especially with regard to the need for ‘double-negation’ of coloniality and nationalism.

Rise of human capital and investment discourses in education

The intellectual roots of thinking about human beings as a form of capital can be traced as far back as late 17th century Britain (Brown, Lauder, and Cheung Citation2020). However, the concept of human capital and the discipline of economics in general had little to do with education until the 1960s. In the context of intensified cold-war economic competition, American economists became preoccupied with identifying the causes and levers to propel economic growth (Holden and Biddle Citation2017). A number of them – most notably Theodore Schultz, Gary Becker and Jacob Mincer – launched ambitious research agendas to demonstrate the role of education in improving workers’ productivity and earnings as well as the nation’s economic growth. The conception of education as an investment in human capital quickly found resonance among American politicians and lobbyists eager to expand the federal government’s role in education. Appearing frequently in congressional hearings, the emerging findings of human capital theorists paved the way for the passage of laws establishing permanent federal involvement in education in mid 1960s (Holden and Biddle Citation2017).

This set of discourses quickly disseminated beyond the U.S. through the activities of international organisations (Holden and Biddle Citation2017). In the 1960s, human capital theory boomed as a transnational research agenda, enabling economists to claim indispensable expertise and authority on education matters (Tan Citation2014). Political leaders in advanced capitalist countries and international organisations quickly absorbed the investment discourse into their efforts to secure increased public funding for domestic education as well as international aid for education in other countries (Brown, Lauder, and Cheung Citation2020; Mundy Citation2008).

With the rise of neoliberalism in the 1970s, human capital theory and the associated investment discourse in education took on new meanings. A series of social crises and the boom of Four Asian Tigers led to the breakdown of the economic nationalism in the Global North that fuelled the development and dissemination of human capital theory in the 1960s (Brown, Lauder, and Cheung Citation2020). Business and political leaders in the Global North quickly formed alliances to promote a neoliberal world order, where inequality would be tolerated as necessary incentive and individuals and firms left to compete without the protection of trade tariffs or social safety nets (Brown, Lauder, and Cheung Citation2020). In this context, the link that human capital theorists established between education and national prosperity enabled researchers to cast failing public educational systems as national crises, evident in the landmark report A Nation at Risk (Gardner et al. Citation1983) in the U.S. The solution they advocated for, however, was privatisation rather than public investment, a sharp contrast to the 1960s (Mundy Citation2008; Shelton Citation2023). Furthermore, through international organisations like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the Global North pressured developing countries to carry out liberalisation reforms such as placing caps on public spending and charging user fees in the name of improving efficiency in the education sector (Alexander Citation2001; Mundy Citation2008).

The advancement of neoliberalism across the globe spurred growing appetites for educational research on how to allocate limited resources most efficiently. As a result, the investment discourse became increasingly prominent in the realm of education policies and international development. Economists launched numerous studies to measure rates of return to education, which international organisations and governments increasingly used as a guide for allocating scarce resources (Klees Citation2016; Psacharopoulos Citation1985). Research on the education production function also grew rapidly, with a focus on assessing the relations between educational inputs and outputs (Levin Citation1989). Though most studies were carried out in advanced capitalist societies in the 1970s and 1980s, international organisations drew on them heavily and uncritically to justify its recipes for education reform in developing countries (Alexander Citation2001).

Notably, the expansion of human capital theory took place despite severe criticism within and outside the economic discipline since its inception. To name a few most prominent ones, Klees (Citation2016) took apart human capital theory on its own terms by demonstrating that its conception of efficiency as well as claims about relations between earnings, productivity and social benefits are untenable. Tan (Citation2014) systematically summarises these criticisms from four different perspectives. Theoretically, its foundation – methodological individualism and rational choice theory – is weak and problematic. Empirically, its claims about the causal relations between education and income or growth often fail to bear out. Practically, it promoted ‘economic imperialism’ (Allais Citation2012), subjugated education to economic needs, and enabled the illusion that education can solve social problems. Morally, it promotes problematic definitions and descriptions of human beings as utility-drive, self-interested animals, obliterating the power relations between capital and labour by recasting labour as a form of capital. More recently, Brown, Lauder, and Cheung (Citation2020) claim the death of orthodox human capital theory and attempt to transform the field from its ashes.

In sum, the conception of education as investment in human capital emerged out of American economists’ attempt to explain and stimulate economic growth. Thanks to the active promotion of Global North governments and the international organisations under their influence, the investment discourse became prominent in educational research and policy and instrumental in justifying neoliberal educational reforms. The histories of the investment discourse in education demonstrates the persistence of the colonial matrix of power (Mignolo Citation2011) in global knowledge production as well as in educational governance: knowledge was produced in response to the concerns of elites in advanced capitalist societies and based on prior knowledge in the colonial core, and then used to justify neo-colonial agendas across the globe. It is in this context that Chinese rural education became an area of international educational research in the global knowledge production towards the end of the 20th century.

The boom of international research on Chinese rural education

While the investment discourse rose to prominence across the globe in the 1960s and 1970s, sinology grew rapidly in Europe and the U.S. as governments and international organisations sought to understand China and scholars increasingly looked to China’s unprecedented social transformations – including the education system – for inspirations to address domestic social problems (Ding Citation1996). However, due to the Cultural Revolution (1966–1976), social science research in China grounded to a halt (Xu Citation2021). Therefore, sinologists of this period primarily relied on document analysis (Ding Citation1996). Despite its growing global prominence, the investment discourse was basically absent in international research on Chinese education during this period.

In 1978, China embarked on the reform era just as neoliberalism gained momentum rapidly across the globe. In the forty-five years that followed (1978–2022), Chinese rural educationFootnote2 emerged and eventually boomed as an area of study in global knowledge production, as did the impact of the investment discourse within this rapidly developing field. As shows, the number of articles about rural education in China published by the 40 journals in our sample grew from 8 between 1978 and 1989 to 124 between 2010 and 2022. The number of articles influenced by the investment discourse grew even more rapidly, its percentage increasing from 12.5% to 34.7%. The idea of ‘human capital’ became so taken-for-granted that researchers no longer needed to explain its meaning or justify its relevance in academic writing, not only in economics but also in many adjacent disciplines and fields. Thirteen articles from other disciplines – such as Hannum et al. (Citation2019) – use the term ‘human capital’ without any explicit explanation, justification, or citation.

Table 1. Growth of international research on Chinese rural education (1978–2022).

In the early reform years, the World Bank played an important role in promoting the investment discourse in international research on Chinese rural education. In the period between 1978 and 1989, the first and only article in our sample with clear connection to the investment discourse – Jamison (Citation1986) – grew out of the World Bank’s first mission to China in 1980, as did most empirical economic analysis of Chinese society published in early and mid 1980s. The main report of this mission discussed educational issues from the perspective of ‘human resources’ (EAPRO Citation1981, xiv). A public health scientist trained at Stanford and Harvard, Dean Jamison participated in this mission as the population, health and nutrition expert. Utilising data obtained during the mission – the height, weight, age and grade-level data of over 3000 children in five different localities – Jamison (Citation1986) argued that malnutrition in rural China was ‘sufficiently prevalent in 1979 to retard the school advancement of large numbers of children’ (299) and that investing in nutrition improvement could potentially save substantial educational resources through reducing the number of students in need of repeating grades (308).

In contrast, the boom of Chinese rural education as an area of international academic research and of the investment discourse in the 2010s was to a large extent driven by Chinese scholars with academic training in the Global North. Among the articles published between 2010 and 2022, 76.6% had first authors with Chinese surnames and 38.7% had first authors affiliated with institutions in mainland China, much higher than previous decades (). These two percentages were higher among the 32 articles framed through the investment discourse from the same period −78.1% and 50%, respectively. However, even in the last decade, the first authors of most articles published in the highly cited journals in our sample obtained their doctorates in the Global North, especially the US ().

The prominent contribution of Chinese scholars with experiences in the Global North reflects heightened academic internationalisation in China. From 1978 to 2019, the number of Chinese students and scholars studying abroad grew from 39,000 to 703,500 (Wang and Miao Citation2022). As the most powerful pole in global knowledge production, the US is the top destination for Chinese students and scholars, followed by other Anglophone countries such as the UK, Australia and Canada (UNESCO Institute for Statistics Citation2024).

Moreover, the Chinese state actively promoted the internationalisation of Chinese humanities and social sciences (Xu Citation2021). Under state mandate to ‘go-out’ and enhance global ‘discourse power’ (National Planning Committee of Philosophy and Social Sciences Citation2011), Chinese research universities enacted various policies to incentivise international publication beginning in the early 2000s. By 2016, 84 out of 116 Chinese top universities set up university-level incentive schemes for humanities and social science scholars to publish in international journals (Xu, Rose, and Oancea Citation2021). These incentive schemes tie monetary reward or career-advancement to publication in journals indexed by the Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI) and the Arts and Humanities Citation Index (A&HCI) (Xu, Rose, and Oancea Citation2021).Footnote3 Under these incentive schemes, most scholars prioritised publication in English-language journals (Xu, Oancea, and Rose Citation2021). As a result, the volume of Chinese social science international publications has been growing quickly (Liu et al. Citation2015).

That the percentage of articles influenced by the investment discourse in our sample nearly triple in the past four decades reflects ‘economics imperialism’ (Allais Citation2012; Tan Citation2014) – the global expansion and dominance of economics vocabulary in social sciences. In China, the discipline of economics is more conducive to and achieved a higher level of internationalisation than most other social science disciplines (Xu, Oancea, and Rose Citation2021). Built upon universalist assumptions like the rational choice model, the investment discourse allows researchers to investigate similar sets of research questions with the same set of tools – developed in Anglo-American contexts – in different societies, without delving into local meanings and contexts.

In sum, our analysis reveals that the Chinese state and Chinese scholars were crucial agents in the boom of the international literature on Chinese rural education as well as on the growing dominance of the investment discourse within it. Attempting to gain global discourse power, the state and its research universities aggressively recruited scholars with overseas academic training and incentivised academics to publish in English-language international journals indexed by SSCI or A&HCI. Under these incentive structures, scholars adopted dominant discourses in English-language academia – like the investment discourse – to examine Chinese rural education. As we will demonstrate in the next section, this growing body of literature reinforces rather than challenges the dominance of western theories and discourses.

Unpacking Chinese rural education through the investment discourse

Among the 38 articles primarily framed through the investment discourse, we identified four major themes: 1) evaluating the return to education among different social groups, 2) analysing the various factors that influence family’s investment in education; 3) assessing the impact of migration on human capital accumulation, and 4) evaluating the impact/cost-efficiency of various interventions, especially through Randomised Controlled Trials (RCTs). In the next four subsections, we describe and unpack each of these themes with a focus on the textual and discursive levels: we delineate the particular discursive and social contexts in which they emerge, deconstruct the key concepts embedded in them and examine the implications of their discursive acts.

Measuring returns to education

With the rise of human capital theory, economists began to estimate rates of return to investment in education in the early 1960s. The conception of education as a form of investment in the productivity of workers naturally led to question of what are the rates of return for investments in education or human capital. In the 1960s and 1970s, economists estimated rates of return to education to explain the economic growth of the 1950s as well as to guide public resource allocation within different sections of education and between education and other sectors (Psacharopoulos Citation1985).

In the 1980s and 1990s, research on return to education boomed as liberalisation policies spread across the globe and income inequality soared in many societies, despite persistent difficulties in obtaining reliable estimates and critiques to its untenable theoretical assumptions (Klees Citation2016; Psacharopoulos and Anthony Patrinos Citation2004). This booming literature contributed to the legitimisation of neoliberal policies and discourses that weaken redistribution, dissemble social safety nets and shift the responsibility of paying for education to individuals. It helped to remake education as a private good: if individuals and families could reap substantial economic returns from schooling, it is only natural to ask them to pay for it.

For economists measuring return to education, China’s collectivist and egalitarian economic policies in the 1970s and the subsequent reforms provided unique opportunities to examine how institutional environments may influence the rate of return for investments in education. In the 1980s, economists started to construct a persistent ‘puzzle’ in China’s economic transformation: despite the tremendous demand for and the scarce supply of college-educated workers, return to education and wage differentials by skill, schooling and occupation in China remained much narrower than those in other developing or developed countries (e.g. Jamison and Van der Gaag Citation1987).

Two articles we examined investigated this ‘puzzle’. Utilising data from a production team in 1977 and the Rural Household Survey conducted by the State Statistical Bureau, Li and Zhang (Citation1998) argue that egalitarian distribution compresses return to education and contributed to the ‘low efficiency’ and final collapse of egalitarian collective farming in China (331). Exploiting a dataset of 200 rural enterprises collected by the Chinese State Council in collaboration with the World Bank (Dong and Putterman Citation1996), Fleisher and Wang (Citation2004) demonstrate that rural enterprises ‘overpay’ production workers, while they ‘underpay’ or ‘exploit’ technical workers relative to profit-maximising benchmarks (Fleisher and Wang Citation2004, 315).

The concept of ‘return to education’ performs the magic of casting education-based income inequality in a positive light, framing it – and to some extent income inequality in general – as beneficial and necessary for the public good. Despite different technical approaches, estimating ‘return to education’ is fundamentally about calculating the extent to which having an additional year or level of education or training enables a worker to earn more. As Klees (Citation2016) critiqued, the assumption that education increases workers’ productivity and that earnings reflect productivity is baked into complex statistical models, rather than examined empirically. The focus on quantifying the private rates of return obscures questions about power and value in educational and economic systems, including those about why economic systems reward some forms of labour and skills (such as those involved in managing assets) more than others (such as those involved in caring for young children). Therefore, it is only fair that those with higher educational levels receive higher incomes. Egalitarian policies that reduce wage differentials constitute ‘exploitation’ of workers with higher skills and discourage families from investing in education (Fleisher and Wang Citation2004, 315). Transforming education-based income inequality into ‘return to education’, these articles helped to legitimise the rapid expansion of economic inequality in the 1990s and early 2000s as China incorporated into the global neoliberal economic system.

As income inequality widened and return to education grew in the 1990s and 2000s, the ‘puzzle’ of low return to education in the early reform years became a historical artefact that gradually drifted out of the spotlight. Nonetheless, the articles we examined continue to measure ‘return to education’ to address new research questions, such as the extent to which increasing returns to education accounted for the expansion of income inequality (Zhou Citation2014) and the economic returns to speaking Mandarin among migrant workers (Gao and Smyth Citation2011). As we demonstrate in the following section, many scholars also utilised the construct in their investigation of the rural education enrolment challenge.

Understanding the rural enrolment challenge

After a decade of empty rhetoric and little action in the 1990s, the Education for All (EFA) movement – aimed at achieving universal primary education – gained momentum in the early 2000s (Mundy Citation2006). Pressured by rising tides of anti-globalisation movements, Global North governments and the multilateral international organisations they support formed a new compact that promoted universal education as the solution for poverty and inequality as well as stalled economic development (Mundy Citation2006, Citation2008). Following two decades of stagnation, international educational aid increased substantially, with some donors beginning to fund recurrent educational costs (such as teacher salaries) in developing countries (Mundy Citation2008).

During the same period, China was working hard to boost rural educational enrolment and accomplish its goal of universal nine-year compulsory education. A newcomer to the globalised market struggling to lift its people out of poverty at the time, China received educational aid from the Global North and international organisations. Bilateral and multilateral aid projects like the Gansu Basic Education Project (Brook, Hu, and Zhao Citation2017) had a tremendous impact on the rural education system in China. At the same time, in the face of widening educational and economic inequality, the state launched a series of reforms to shift away from localised to more centralised educational financing models. The state started to provide free textbooks in rural communities in western region in 2001; the Two Exemptions One Subsidy (TEOS) policy – exempting tuition fees and book fees and providing room and board subsidies for rural students – was implemented in less developed western regions in spring 2006; compulsory education became free for all students enrolled in their places of household registration in 2008 (Lou and Ross Citation2008).

Aligned with the aforementioned domestic and international contexts, seven articles published between 2001 and 2015 in our sample focus on identifying factors that limit or promote basic educational enrolment in rural communities, such as poverty (e.g. Brown and Park Citation2002), family health shocks (Sun and Yao Citation2010), child gender (Song, Appleton, and Knight Citation2006), child nutrition (Zhao and Glewwe Citation2010) and school quality (e.g. Shi et al. Citation2015). These articles are based on statistical analysis of extensive survey datasets collected by Chinese state agencies or research teams with international partnerships.

Deeply embedded in the investment discourse, these articles treat education as human capital investment and educational enrolment as reflecting rural families’ ‘demand for schooling’ (e.g. Zhao and Glewwe Citation2010, 452) without any explicit justification. Taking for granted the rational choice model widely assumed in economic theories, authors draw on the concept of ‘return to education’ to varying degrees to explain low enrolment rate or high dropout rates – interpreted as low ‘demand for schooling’ – in rural communities. For instance, Song, Appleton, and Knight (Citation2006) argue that human capital investment for girls was lower for rural girls because ‘there appears to be no monetary return to schooling for women’ and that there was a ‘higher opportunity cost when enrolling young women than when enrolling young men’ (1639). Shi et al. (Citation2015) was the only study that included a qualitative component (interviewing 52 students) and amended the rational choice assumption with the note that students and families often made decisions due to short-term psychological stressors rather than based on cost–benefit analysis.

Based on empirical analysis, these articles propose a wide variety of state interventions from removing credit constraints or reducing cost (Brown and Park Citation2002) and providing health insurance (Sun and Yao Citation2010) to subsidising female education (Song, Appleton, and Knight Citation2006). Compared to the articles about the ‘return to education puzzle’ that legitimised economic inequality, they utilised a similar set of discursive construction to reveal how social and economic inequalities constrained rural families’ investment in primary and secondary education. Nevertheless, with the conception of education as investment, the analysis and recommendations they present construct the problem of rural education as an economic one, obscuring the political, cultural and social dynamics that prevent rural children and their families from engaging meaningfully in formal education.

Assessing the impact of parental migration on human capital accumulation

Western social scientists and international development agencies have long been concerned with and divided about the impact of migration on human capital and economic development. On the one hand, neo-classical economists exhibited great optimism about the role of migration in facilitating the transfer of financial capital and skills; on the other hand, structuralist scholars expressed concerns about brain drains – the extraction of human capital from underdeveloped communities to developed ones – a phenomenon that they argued led to ‘asymmetric growth’ and the reinforcement of centre-periphery dependency development model (de Haas Citation2010). Between the contrasting poles of optimistic neo-classical and pessimistic structuralist views, the 1980s and 1990s witnessed the emergence of the New Economics of Labour Migration (NELM) (de Haas Citation2010). Recognising the importance of broader social and economic contexts, focusing on migrants’ households rather than individuals as decision-making units, and incorporating livelihood approaches and transnational perspectives, NELM broadened the neo-classical economic analysis of migration and witnessed another surge in optimism about migration and development in the 2000s (de Haas Citation2010; Stark Citation1991).

In this international discursive context, a large body of literature emerged in the 2010s to assess the impact of parental migration on human capital accumulation among rural children in China. As market-oriented reforms deepened and restrictions on labour migration relaxed in the 1990s, China began to witness rapidly growing rural-to-urban migration of perhaps the largest scale in recorded human history. In 2010, more than 221 million people were residing outside the city of their household registration, an 81% increase from 2000 (National Bureau of Statistics Citation2011). In 2020, the number reached 376 million, more than a quarter of China’s total population (National Bureau of Statistics Citation2021). Due to hukou-based restrictions on access to public services including education, the children of migrant families either became migrant children, who encounter barriers in accessing public educational resources in their migration destination, or left-behind children, who remained in rural communities separated from one or both migrating parents (Wu Citation2011).

A total of 15 articles among our full sample of 171 examines the impact of this massive rural-to-urban migration on children. Eight of them framed their research questions through the investment discourse, constructing children’s cognitive development, health and academic attainment as indicators of human capital. Aligned with the approach of NELM, these articles are attentive to socioeconomic context, tend to examine the household rather than the individual and seek to uncover factors contributing to the inequities in migration systems. Overall, they demonstrate that parental migration is a double-edged sword for children’s human capital accumulation: it increases the financial resources that families could invest in children’s education (Y. Dong et al. Citation2021) while taking a toll on the cognitive development and academic achievement of rural left-behind children (e.g. Bai et al. Citation2022). Based on these empirical findings, several authors advocated for public investment in ‘compensatory programs’ (Hongliang et al. Citation2014, 193) to ameliorate the various negative impacts on human capital accumulation among rural children.

Notably, these eight articles are scattered in rural studies, development studies and demography journals, indicating the penetration of the investment discourse in these interdisciplinary fields. Analysing ‘parental migration’ as an independent variable in regression models about child outcomes, these articles transform structural inequalities into individual disadvantages or deficiencies. The focus of analysis as well as intervention is on the ‘cognitive delay’ (Bai et al. Citation2022, 1), suboptimal health and underachievement of rural left-behind children, rather than on the exclusion of migrant children in urban school systems or growing rural-urban and socioeconomic inequalities that deprived them of parental companionship and high-quality education in the first place. Therefore, despite their apparent concern for rural children and acknowledgement of social inequalities, this line of research ultimately conceals the social structures that place rural children and families in subordinate positions.

Cost-efficiency of policies and interventions

The fourth cluster of articles analyses the effectiveness or input-output efficiency of various policies and intervention aimed at enhancing human capital accumulation. Mostly published in development studies and economics journals, the eleven articles in this cluster examined policy interventions including vision screening and eyeglasses (e.g. Glewwe, Park, and Zhao Citation2016), treated drinking water (Zhang and Colin Xu Citation2016), school-based health programs (Sylvia et al. Citation2013), early commitment of financial aid (e.g. C. Liu et al. Citation2011), computer assisted learning (e.g. Bai et al. Citation2023), voucher programs (Wong et al. Citation2013), and pay-for-percentile teacher incentive schemes (Chang et al. Citation2020). The outcomes that they measure as indicators of human capital accumulation include academic achievement, educational enrolment or attainment and health.

Most articles in this cluster utilised data from RCTs, the golden standard of causal inference in economics (Leigh Citation2018). The first wave of RCT popularity in development economics began in the 1960s and came to a stall in the 1980s due to pervasive political resistance to random assignment of social assistance (de SouzaLeão and Eyal Citation2019). The second wave began in the 2000s and grew much faster with a different set of partners (non-governmental organisations and philanthro-capitalists rather than government donors) and interventions (small-scale, short-term and well-bounded interventions rather than large social programs) (de SouzaLeão and Eyal Citation2019). By the 2010s, two-thirds of impact evaluations in development economics used RCTs (Leigh Citation2018).

Emerging in the 2010s, the RCT articles we examined are part of this ongoing second wave. Notably, members, affiliates and partners of the Rural Education Action Project (REAP) at Stanford University contributed to seven articles (64%) in this cluster and at least five more articles in the rest of our sample. Established in 2006, REAP carried out numerous RCTs on rural and migrant children in China through close partnership with the Centre for Chinese Agricultural Policy (CCAP) at the Chinese Academy of Sciences and a research team at Shaanxi Normal University.

Compared to policy recommendations proposed in aforementioned articles about the rural enrolment challenge and the impact of migration, the interventions that these articles focus on are more limited in scope and of a technical nature. In fact, the very success of the second wave of RCT studies stems from its ability to mitigate uncertainty with the claim to reliable causal inference and to reframe contentious social problems as ostensibly technical challenges (Berndt Citation2015; Donovan Citation2018). As de SouzaLeão and Eyal (Citation2019) argue, these ‘nudge-type’ and ‘short-term’ interventions enable the second wave of RCT studies to circumvent political opposition and act as a ‘hinge’ between academic researchers and international development donors (385).

Similar to the articles on parental migration, these policy and program evaluation studies construct migrant and rural children as deficient in human capital and in need of compensatory intervention. They problematise and seek to address the deficiencies of rural children and families, rather than the social structures that hindered their flourishing. In spite of their seemingly benign intention, policies aimed at increasing the human capital of rural children could exacerbate rather than ameliorate existing structural inequalities. China’s ‘suzhi education’ (education for quality) reform initiated in the early 2000s is a case in point. Aiming to improve its citizens’ human capital and stimulate economic development in the face of increasing global competition, the Chinese state launched ‘suzhi education’ reforms to support the shift from labour-intensive to globally competitive knowledge economy (Lou Citation2022). However, demanding increased financial investment and social and cultural capital from children and families, the new curriculum inadvertently reproduces and exacerbates existing gaps in educational experiences and outcomes between urban and rural children (Lou Citation2022). Therefore, it reinforces neoliberal logics through obscuring rather than addressing the structural inequalities that rural communities are trapped in and attributing their educational struggles and failures to individuals and families.

Conclusions

We closely examine the emergence and growth of Chinese rural education as an area of international research since 1978. In the preceding sections, we have demonstrated that human capital theory and the investment discourse became a major ‘hinge’ (de SouzaLeão and Eyal Citation2019) between gatekeepers in global academic knowledge production enterprises and aspiring Chinese institutions and researchers, thanks to their alignment with neoliberalism and focus on technical rather than political problems. The articles we examined respond more to salient debates and prevalent trends in global academic discourses than to the concerns and needs of local communities. Most of them grew out of intensified academic internationalisation in China in the 21st century, which the Chinese state considers a crucial element of the nation’s ‘soft power’ (Xu Citation2021). Authors – most of whom bear Chinese surnames and possess academic training in the Global North – collect empirical data from rural children, families and schools in China to produce articles that refine neo-classical economic theories and reinforce their hegemonic status. Written in the English language and academic economics vocabularies, these texts were produced for researchers, policy makers and international development professionals in the Global North while effectively excluding most domestic scholars, practitioners and policy makers from the conversation.

Our findings are aligned with Trahar et al. (Citation2019)’s analysis of ongoing colonisation in academic writing due to the dominance of English language in scholarly journals as well as the prevalence of ‘metropolitan’ genres of scholarly writing and discourse. This extends to the ways in which certain bodies of knowledge maintain their supremacy and privilege. Scholars from beyond the English-speaking core are compelled not only to craft their work in English for mainstream journal publication, but also to situate their work within a ‘metropolitan discourse’ that may not be suitable for their specific context. The outcome is an ‘increasing gap between ‘locally produced knowledge’ and the ‘knowledge needed by local society’ (Kang Citation2009, 198).

Therefore, it is perhaps no surprise that many original and important theoretical contributions from Chinese scholars did not make it into English-language academic publications, not to mention the highly cited journals in our sample. For instance, Wang (Citation2009) points out that human capital theory overlooks the transaction costs between educators and learners and obliterates crucial differences among different educational systems. Focusing on the perspective of education providers, Wang (Citation2009) constructs a ‘new human capital theory’ based on three different prototypes of public education – church schools (学在教堂), guild-based apprenticeships (学在行会), and imperial examination and school systems (学在庙堂). She differentiates between productive versus distributive human capital (which leads to economic productivity versus power or status in distributive systems like imperial courts and nation states) as well as between private and collective human capital (which becomes less versus more valuable when other people acquire it). Restoring the social and political nature of educational enterprises in economic analysis, this critical perspective offers compelling explanations for complex educational and social phenomena in China and beyond.

Notably, with new state mandates, Chinese humanities and social sciences began to shift away from uncritical pursuit of SSCI publications towards constructing independent knowledge systems in the past few years, with an emphasis on centring domestic problems, utilising traditional Chinese cultural resources and critical engagement with other knowledge systems (Zhai Citation2022; Teng and Wang Citation2023). In light of our findings, this move is both necessary and perilous. On the one hand, constructing – or restoring – autonomous knowledge systems that respond to the needs of local communities and build upon indigenous wisdoms is crucial for the pursuit of decoloniality in China and beyond. Scholars in Zimbabwe, for instance, engaged in an anticolonial project to challenge colonial structures in knowledge production through ‘reclaiming, rethinking, reconstituting, rewriting, and validating indigenous knowledge and languages, and repositioning them as integral parts of the academy’ (Shizha Citation2010, 115). On the other hand, the pursuit of independent knowledge system is complicated by the current Chinese leadership’s active endeavours to bolster China’s global influence and make the Chinese knowledge system a competitive, if not superior, counterpart to the Western one. Amidst precarious global politics and surging waves of nationalism, we are mindful of how these efforts may lead to dewesternisation (Mignolo Citation2011) and delinking from or denial of other knowledge systems (Shahjahan Citation2005) rather than the dynamic coexistence of plural knowledges that decolonial scholars strive towards. Therefore, for comparative educational scholars with decolonial visions in China and elsewhere, it is pivotal to grapple with the intertwined complexities of coloniality and nationalism, as this special issue emphasises.

Supplemental material

Supplemental Material

Download MS Word (18.4 KB)Supplemental Material

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful for research assistance provided by Zhujun Jiang, Jiaxin Zhou and Fanshu Gong and for the insightful comments of Ting Wang, Licui Chen, You Yun, Jin Jin and two anonymous reviewers. They would also like to acknowledge the indispensable care and labor of family members within the household – Zhenping Liu, Yonglan Huang, Bingting Yu, Dingcheng Xiang, Dingchun Xiang, Guanyang Zhang – in making this work possible.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Supplementary material

Supplemental data for this article can be accessed online at https://doi.org/10.1080/03057925.2024.2429836.

Additional information

Funding

This work was supported by National Social Science Fund of China under Grant [CDA230331] (History and Transformation of International Academic Discourses around Chinese Education).

Notes

1. The total number of articles described in this paper differs slightly from Xiang et al. (Citation2023) due to refinement of article inclusion and coding criteria in the second phase of the study.

2. We follow the Chinese convention of including the study of rural-to-urban migrant children and schools in the field of ‘rural education’.

3. The Chinese state began to turn away from these policies and instead promote domestic publications towards the end of the 2010s.

References

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.